The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate

Post originally Published November 10, 2023 || Last Updated November 11, 2023

See how everyone can now afford to fly Business Class and book 5 Star Hotels with Mighty Travels Premium! Get started for free.


The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - What Are Swipe Fees and Why Are They Controversial?


Swipe fees, also known as interchange fees, are transaction fees paid by merchants to card issuers like banks and credit card companies each time a customer pays with a credit or debit card. The fee is usually around 1-3% of the total transaction amount.

These fees add up to tens of billions of dollars per year and are a major source of revenue for card issuers. But many retailers argue the fees are excessive and drive up costs that get passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices.
The battle over swipe fees has raged for years between merchants and card issuers. It peaked in 2010 with the passage of the Dodd-Frank Act, which placed caps on debit card swipe fees.

However, credit card swipe fees remain unregulated, to the continued frustration of many retailers. Groups like the Merchants Payments Coalition, which represents major retailers, have lobbied extensively for lower fees.
Card issuers like Visa and Mastercard defend the fees as critical to funding the card rewards and benefits consumers value. They say merchants benefit from guaranteed payment and increased sales generated by cards.
The swipe fee debate essentially boils down to who ultimately pays the costs of card transactions. Card issuers argue it's fair for merchants to pay, since they benefit from card spending. But merchants believe card fees should be incorporated into interest rates and cardholder fees instead of being offloaded onto all consumers.
Until recently, few consumers were even aware of swipe fees and how they work. But as the battle has heated up, more attention is being drawn to this controversial aspect of the payments system.

What else is in this post?

  1. The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - What Are Swipe Fees and Why Are They Controversial?
  2. The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Swipe Fee Reform: Consumer Advocates vs. Card Issuers
  3. The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Will Lower Swipe Fees Really Benefit Consumers?
  4. The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Examining Claims of Job Losses and Economic Harm
  5. The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Australia's Experience with Swipe Fee Regulation
  6. The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Weighing the Costs and Benefits of Government Intervention
  7. The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Alternatives to Regulating Swipe Fees Directly
  8. The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - The Outlook for Swipe Fee Reform in the Current Political Climate

The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Swipe Fee Reform: Consumer Advocates vs. Card Issuers


The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate

The battle over swipe fee reform has created some strange bedfellows, with consumer advocacy groups finding themselves allied with major retailers in pushing for regulation. Groups like Consumer Action, Consumer Federation of America and the National Consumers League have urged Congress to enact policies to cut swipe fees.

They argue that excessive card fees drive up costs for merchants, which then get passed on to consumers through higher retail prices. By lowering swipe fees, they claim overall costs in the economy would come down.
A 2010 report by Consumer Action estimated that swipe fees cost the average household $427 per year through higher prices. The groups also dispute claims by banks that lower fees would hurt card reward programs, arguing issuers could simply cut profits instead.

On the other side, card issuers have teamed up with some pro-business organizations to oppose regulating swipe fees. Groups like the American Bankers Association, American Financial Services Association and the U.S. Chamber of Commerce counter that swipe fees reflect the value consumers get from electronic payments.
They warn that capping fees could backfire on consumers by reducing card benefits and potentially even limiting access to credit. When Australia slashed credit card swipe fees in 2003, banks trimmed reward programs substantially.
The card lobby also rejects the idea that swipe fees drive up retail prices. Since cards increase sales volume for merchants, the groups argue that merchants benefit more than they lose from card fees.
Behind these arguments, both sides are really advancing their own financial interests. Consumer groups see swipe fees as an opportunity to achieve a 'big win' against banks by hyping up the consumer angle.

For the card industry, it's ultimately about protecting a major profit center that brings in tens of billions per year. Their coalition with pro-business groups gives them added lobbying muscle.
This ideological standoff has made substantive swipe fee reform an uphill battle. Until consumers are more engaged on the issue, politicians have limited incentive to champion any major changes despite retailer pressure.

The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Will Lower Swipe Fees Really Benefit Consumers?


The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate

The big question in the swipe fee debate is whether lowering the fees would actually benefit consumers or just merchants' bottom lines. Retailers argue that excessive card fees get passed on through higher prices that all shoppers pay. But card issuers dispute that logic as simplistic. The impact on consumers is far more complex.

On one hand, supporters of fee caps model that prices would decrease across the board if swipe fees declined. The Merchants Payments Coalition claims that swipe fees cost U.S. households an average of $427 annually through higher retail costs. In Australia, prices did fall slightly in some sectors after fees were cut in 2003.

However, there’s no conclusive proof that fee reductions translate directly into lower prices. In competitive markets, retailers may just pocket the savings as higher profits. Some financial analysts argue that swipe fees are already “baked in” to retail business models and have limited impact on pricing.
There’s also debate around how lower fees would impact card rewards programs. Banks warn that capping swipe fees would force them to cut back on rewards, which consumers clearly value. But consumer groups counter that banks could simply accept lower profits instead.
The reality is murkier. Reward programs might not disappear entirely but could be significantly devalued. That happened in Australia and Canada after fee caps were introduced. Such a change would disappoint card users who rely on miles and points to subsidize vacations and other large purchases.
Access to credit could also be squeezed if banks take in less swipe fee revenue. Critics dismiss this concern as overblown. But there is a real possibility that some marginal borrowers would see lower credit limits or fewer card options if issuers pull back lending.

The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Examining Claims of Job Losses and Economic Harm


One of the most contested issues in the swipe fee debate is whether lowering the fees would lead to major job losses and economic damage, as the card industry warns. This question matters greatly in swaying public policy. If true, it would undermine the argument that regulating swipe fees benefits society overall.

Card issuers like Visa and Mastercard claim that restricting their fee income through regulation would force them to cut costs dramatically in ways that could hurt the economy. Specifically, they argue that tens of thousands of jobs could be eliminated if swipe fee revenue declines.

For example, Visa has claimed that the Durbin Amendment, which capped debit card swipe fees, cost the company thousands of jobs. The card networks also funded a study warning that over 20,000 jobs could be lost from a drop in swipe fee earnings.
However, consumer advocates dispute those figures as exaggerated and misleading. They point out that card issuers are immensely profitable, with net margins commonly around 25-30%. Issuers could easily absorb moderate fee declines through lower profits rather than job cuts, argues the retail lobby.

As precedent, swipe fee regulation in Australia did not trigger mass layoffs, though banks did report a hit to profits. The Merchants Payments Coalition, which supports fee regulation, claims the Durbin Amendment had no impact on credit card issuers’ employment levels despite their predictions. The industry employs far fewer people than the retail sector.
Still, there are legitimate concerns that restricting swipe fees could potentially reduce jobs, at least around the margins. One analysis found that the Durbin cap was associated with around 5,000 job losses in industries supporting card issuers. The compound economic effects are hard to predict.

Financial industry advocates also contend that the well-paid jobs within the card sector contribute high value to the economy. If issuers scale back certain areas like analytics, fraud prevention or technology, it could negatively impact innovation.
Overall the employment impact of swipe fee reform remains hotly disputed. More independent research is needed to weigh the competing claims. Given the card industry's profitability, massive job losses seem exaggerated. But some drag on employment and growth is plausible if fees decline sharply.

The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Australia's Experience with Swipe Fee Regulation


Australia’s 2003 reforms shine critical light on swipe fee caps’ actual impact. The country slashed credit card interchange fees by up to 50%, from around 0.95% to 0.5-0.6% on average. This intervention established Australia as the first major market to regulate card fees directly.

Seventeen years later, Australia’s experience offers intriguing lessons for the U.S. policy debate. Consumer advocates portray it as a policy success that delivered cost savings. But Australian banks maintain the reforms hurt consumers more than helped. The truth lies somewhere in between.
On the plus side, merchants welcomed the fee reduction. Australian retailers had faced the highest card fees in the world. One survey found that 59% of merchants saw their costs decrease following the reforms. Prices also edged down slightly in the grocery and retail sectors as marketing costs fell.

However, banks offset revenue declines by cutting back card rewards programs and benefits. Issuers slashed points redemption values by 35-50% almost immediately after the reforms took effect. They also increased annual fees on premium cards by up to 70%.
Economists dispute whether lower merchant fees translated into consumer savings overall. One study found negligible impact on most retail prices as merchants pocketed gains. With less lucrative points programs, consumers may have ended up worse off.
Importantly, the reforms did not trigger mass credit contraction as U.S. banks warn. Consumer credit expanded steadily despite lower bank revenue. Yet some analysts argue tighter lending did deprive marginal borrowers of access. This effect was likely modest though.

The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Weighing the Costs and Benefits of Government Intervention


The heated swipe fee debate inevitably raises questions of whether lawmakers should intervene directly to regulate card fees. Proponents argue regulation is justified to restrain anti-competitive practices by dominant card networks. But critics counter that meddling carries too many unintended consequences. There are reasonable cases on both sides.

Government intervention could clearly benefit merchants through immediate fee reductions. Retailers maintain that current swipe fee levels far exceed the actual cost of processing transactions, reflecting lack of competition. Compelling Visa and Mastercard to lower interchange rates would deliver them significant savings. Whether those savings get passed on to consumers is less certain.
Still, regulation poses major risks that policymakers must weigh carefully. For starters, capping swipe fees might simply end up redistributing costs onto consumers. As banks lose fee revenue, they could look to recoup it by cutting rewards programs, raising interest rates and curtailing access to credit. Those would be extremely unpopular moves.

There are also concerns that blunt fee regulation could backfire by undermining innovation. The complex economics behind card networks are little understood, even by experts. Moderating card fees through regulatory fiat might have unintended second-order effects. For instance, weaker incentives for issuers could slow development of advanced anti-fraud technologies that benefit all users.

Perhaps the biggest fear is that fee regulation sets a troubling precedent of government micro-managing free markets. Once lawmakers start dictating fees in one industry, it becomes a slippery slope to intervene in others. The law of unintended consequences looms large.
The alternative view is that card fees cry out for regulatory oversight after years of escalation. Visa and Mastercard control 80% of credit card volume, underscoring their monopoly-like status. Letting them dictate interchange terms to merchants seems innately unfair. Regulation could check their rent-seeking power.
However, others argue that merchants accept card fees voluntarily for the value provided. Consumers ultimately drive payment preferences. If cards did not benefit merchants through higher sales, they would refuse them. The card networks' dominance was earned through major investments, not unfair practices.

The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - Alternatives to Regulating Swipe Fees Directly


Rather than imposing top-down fee caps through legislation, some experts advocate exploring alternatives that preserve market incentives while empowering merchants. Though regulation seems the most direct route to lowering swipe fees, its risks and unintended consequences give pause. More modest, targeted reforms could strike a better cost-benefit balance.
One option is limiting anti-competitive practices by the dominant card networks through existing antitrust laws. For instance, merchants could gain leverage to negotiate lower interchange rates if Visa and Mastercard relaxed “no surcharge” rules that prevent retailers from passing on card fees directly to customers. Allowing differentiated pricing for cash versus card payments would enable merchants to apply pressure in a free market-oriented way.

Another approach is regulating network exclusivity, whereby certain big banks maintain exclusive arrangements with Visa or Mastercard that bar them from issuing cards on rival networks. These exclusive deals stifle competition that could place downward pressure on swipe fees. Barring exclusivity requirements could disrupt the entrenched duopoly power enjoyed by Visa and Mastercard.
Some reformers also advocate equalizing the interchange fees charged on different card tiers. Currently, premium rewards cards carry higher swipe fees of 2-3%, subsidizing the perks of affluent users at the expense of all merchants and shoppers. Putting mass-market and premium cards on the same interchange schedule would help trim fat from the system.
Improving transparency around swipe fees could further aid merchants’ negotiating position without direct rate-setting. Many small business owners do not even realize they pay interchange fees or understand how card networks set these rates. Requiring issuers to disclose their fees and rate-setting methodology in plain language would empower merchants to make informed decisions.

The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate - The Outlook for Swipe Fee Reform in the Current Political Climate


The Credit Card Swipe Fee Smackdown: Separating Fact from Fiction on This Heated Debate

The battle over swipe fee reform has raged for over a decade now, but the current political climate suggests major federal action remains unlikely in the near future. Despite continued lobbying by retailers, the winds in Washington are not blowing favorably for disruptive legislation capping interchange fees. However, more modest regulatory measures or state-level initiatives could gain some traction.
The big obstacle is that swipe fee regulation proposals garner limited public support. Most consumers are uninformed about interchange fees and fail to see big banks as bad actors. Without grassroots political momentum, Congress has little incentive to pick a fight with the deep-pocketed card industry. Measures like Senator Durbin’s 2009 amendment succeeded partly because public antipathy toward big banks peaked after the financial crisis bailouts. But anger has dissipated as economic stability returned.
Another barrier is the Republican Party’s free market ideology and close ties to corporate interests. The business community leans heavily against fee regulation, arguing it would set a dangerous precedent of government rate-setting. With several major card issuers headquartered in Delaware and South Dakota, home-state Republican lawmakers have been lobbied aggressively. Bipartisan compromise seems unlikely given the polarized climate.
However, some see potential for bipartisan cooperation around alternative reforms like banning anti-competitive card network rules. Allowing merchants to surcharge or steer customers toward cheaper payment methods resonates as a free market solution. Truly egregious card issuer behaviors could attract populist anger from both sides. But massive disruption of the payments ecosystem remains improbable given the risks involved.

The state level may offer more openings to advance reform. States like California, New York and Texas have large economies that confer leverage over card networks. Legislation targeting specific practices like exclusivity deals or interchange tiers could gain traction in progressive states, pressuring national networks to modify policies broadly. But fragmented state measures could also backfire by creating compliance headaches.

See how everyone can now afford to fly Business Class and book 5 Star Hotels with Mighty Travels Premium! Get started for free.